NUMBERS ARE PEOPLE COCK-UP BEFORE CONSPIRACY • CITE PRIMARY SOURCES OR GO HOME


Thursday 13 August 2015

STATPORN, STATPIMPS, STATWHORES PART II: THE ROAD TO GREEK STATISTICS

In this second part to my post, I try to explain the factors behind the decline and corruption of Greek statistics leading up to the 2009 deficit revision, and what it can teach us about Greece, Europe, and the State.

Goodhart's Law

Let's start with the basics: Goodhart's Law. It's reason number #45608 why centrally planned economies do not tend to work:
Goodhart’s “law” [...] stipulates that “any observed statistical regularity will tend to collapse once pressure is placed upon it for control purposes” [...] (Koen and Van den Noord 2005)
"when a measure becomes a target, it ceases to be a good measure."
Dame Ann Marilyn Strathern 
Normally, Government deficits are among the most closely monitored government statistics out there, and come with monthly targets; if Goodhart's Law holds, then it makes sense that they should be some of the most prone to manipulation. We don't know how they compare to other statistics but we know they are tampered with, at least in the Eurozone, as a result of political incentives subject to both economic and political cycles, and within the scope allowed by incomplete fiscal transparency. A number of studies demonstrate this conclusively, but I would single out Koen and Van de Noord (2005), Beetsma et al (2011), de Castro et al (2011) or Alt et al (2014) as the most useful. Readers may have others to contribute; all are welcome.

It takes constant vigilance to keep deficit figures relevant and free from interference - in fact, it is a job for institutions of fiscal governance and transparency, not for the occasional do-gooder. You might think Greece's historical record in this has always been poor, but you'd be wrong. As the IMF acknowledges, fiscal transparency was written into Greece's first constitution and elements of it were in place even during the Revolution. This is because the Greek state, born as it was out of war and a concerted Western nation-building effort, was dependent on foreign loans from day minus one. Subsequently, we spent decades under fiscal monitoring and monetary straitjackets of some sort or other (on which, read Tuncer (2009) and Lazaretou (2004)).

The Stability and Growth Pact

But what happens when institutions are as wrong as the people they're supposed to control? In Greece's case, the key institution was the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP) and its infamous 3% deficit target. Pina and Venes (2007) demonstrate that the SGP increased the tendency of governments to flatter their deficit forecasts. Alt at al (2014), moreover, demonstrate that the influence of the SGP reduced headline deficits but increased stock-flow adjustments, and particularly the disguising of deficits as equity injections into state-controlled enterprises. This stock-flow adjustment effect only occurred in countries with low levels of fiscal transparency. Unfortunately for us, Greece's recent record in this regard was poor, whatever our history might have prepared us for.

Differences of degree and of quality

These were in fact Eurozone-wide problems. All studies mentioned so far find the same problems when Greece is removed from the data. So what was special about Greece? For one, there are differences of degree. Tables 4 and 5 here  and Figure 1 here demonstrate that Greece has been an outlier in terms of downward revisions to the deficit figures, ever since 1997, with revisions typically doubling our deficits. The effect of accounting distortions on Greek deficit figures was typically three times the size of the distortions of the next worst-performing country.


As you can see in the graph to the right, the SGP (in effect from 98 onwards) was an effective constraint mostly on Greek governments' planned deficits - these were indeed never above the 3% ceiling. First releases were also subject to SGP; and although these would always revise the planned balances downward (2000 and 2006 were the sole exceptions), the size of the revision was more or less random, or subject to unforeseen circumstances such as the 2004 Olympics running much further over-budget than expected. Such revisions occasionally breached the 3% target. But it was the ex-post reviews, based on methodological visits and Eurostat interventions, that restored Greek deficits to a persistent, downward trajectory. The reason for this is that ex-post deficit figures weren't just about revisions due to random events or
within the bounds of good practice. They were all about gimmicks. Pg 28 here details the full list of accounting gimmicks used in the years leading up to 2005, and it really takes the whole page to go over them.

So what was the hard constraint on our deficits?

If the SGP was not a hard constraint on Greece's true deficits, did politicians see anything as a hard constraint? An OECD review of budgeting in Greece, prepared on the very eve of the crisis and two years ahead of the 2009 deficit revision, is clear on how things worked. Budgeting was a bottom-up, line-by-line as opposed to programme-by-programme process, planning for only one year at a time, leaving almost no role for Parliamentary control and with no provision for ex post oversight. Accounting became increasingly poor as one moved away from central government. Even the OECD had to concede that accrual accounting was not an immediate priority since the state was bad enough at cash accounting. Audit needed to be strengthened. But perhaps most telling is the way the OECD describes the relationship between the SGP targets and the actual budget (see p 14):
"for the medium term (t+2 and t+3), forecasts are done annually for the Stability and Growth Programme that the Greek government must deliver to the EU in the autumn each year. The medium-term forecast is not updated as part of the budget preparation process in the spring. The overall position of the central government finances is updated centrally using the new forecast. One feature of the forecasting process is the overall fiscal targets that the Greek government decides to reach in the medium-term Stability and Growth Programme forecasts. If the fiscal targets (deficit, expenditures, revenues) are not reached according to an updated medium-term forecast, unspecified or partly specified “reforms” are added (such as a reduction in tax evasion or government expenditures), without these reforms being specified in concrete detail. The macroeconomic forecasts are not used in the line ministries’ budget preparations; rather, as discussed below, they develop their own forecasts. This practice naturally hampers the use of the estimates and indeed undermines the integrity of the budget." 
As K. Featherstone, a long-time Greece-watcher argues, SGP compliance did make a difference but of a very different kind: it strengthened the hand of Greek finance ministers against their colleagues, at least in their short term:
The Maastricht convergence criteria and the Stability and Growth Pact set clear policy parameters and created an external discipline for monetary policy in Greece. At home, the government was empowered: the legitimacy of the EU and the precision of the convergence criteria carried a difficult process of adjustment forward. [...] ultimately the strength of the domestic reform initiative would very probably have run aground without the Maastricht constraint. It was telling that, [...] in 2002 [...][t]he Simitis government did not call for a lessening of this external discipline: presumably, it saw advantages in having the corset. It was a means of strengthening its domestic position when pressing for difficult reform.  
I would argue that, in the post-Maastricht era, the ultimate constraint was not the SGP targets, or the government's deficit forecasts. The true targets were the Government's cash targets; these were constrained by a combination of tax revenue and 'safe' borrowing. Notice, in the OECD's 2008 review of Greek budgeting, how much more regular, robust, integrated and closely monitored the cash targets were than the actual budget and the SGP targets.
The process of cash management includes the preparation of the “budget expenditure implementation plan” and of the “cash plan”. Both plans are backed up by the monthly cash limit decision. The “budget expenditure implementation plan” shows monthly forecasts of expenditures. It is prepared for the entire fiscal year, and is updated and rolled over on a monthly basis. The plan is based on the budget appropriations. The monthly forecasts are prepared by using the assumptions underlying the budget preparation and monthly historical data. The “cash plan” puts the “budget expenditure implementation plan” in the context of the revenue forecasts. It is on a pure cash basis and shows daily cash inflows and outflows from the “Single Treasury Account”. [...] The “cash plan” is reviewed and updated every day for the whole month and every month for the whole year. [emphasis mine] The monitoring system includes a continuous flow of data from the Treasury’s departments, the Central Bank, the Fiscal Audit Offices, and the local Tax and Payment Offices. The “cash plan” is a tool for ensuring that there will be adequate cash balances to meet the budget obligations. The forecasts of the cash plan are used for decisions on borrowing and for investing the cash surpluses. The forecasts are elaborated and a ministerial decision is issued, defining a monthly cash limit for every unit involved. Fiscal Audit Offices and Tax and Payment Offices are required to ask for special approval before payments above a certain amount are made (EUR 3 million). The limits are checked against the monthly outcome data and crosschecked against information received on a daily basis by the Central Bank.
The cash constraint was much harder than the SGP's 3% target. But it was soft in another, more insidious way. Tax revenues may have looked steady but they were vulnerable to erosion and the political cycle; market financing was based on a colossal, global mispricing of risk.

We can test some of this insight empirically. A reasonable number of studies have looked into the causal link between tax revenue and government spending in Greece. The question common to all is whether we followed a 'tax and spend' model, whereby government sets its spending target based on what it can raise through taxes, or a 'spend and tax' model, whereby government sets its spending target based on politics and then scrambles to raise the taxes to pay for it. You can see my selection of studies for yourselves below:
This is by no means the last word on the matter, but it seems to me that Greece operated a 'spend and tax' model (i.e. government set a spending target first and then adjusted taxes to fund this) for most of our modern history - but  switched to a strange type of cash-and spend policy post-Maastricht, which counted any borrowing we thought we could draw on without inviting undue attention as equivalent to tax revenue. It was the sum of this plus actual tax revenues which led government spending post-Maastricht.

Un-gaming Europe's deficits

People often wonder why, if Greece was only an extreme case of a much wider problem, Eurostat called for changes to European countries' deficit calculations in such a piecemeal manner, review by review, rather than demand that everything be restored to the appropriate level of accuracy at once. Part of the story has to do with the fact that Eurostat's powers and capabilities changed as a result of the Greek crisis - it did not always know what changes needed to be made, nor could it impose changes.

You see, back when our original 2009 deficit figures and the first revised 2009 deficit figures were released, Eurostat did not have auditing powers over national statistics agencies. It only got those in June 2010, because, and I quote, 'in 2005 [when this was originally proposed] several key member states were opposed to a strengthening of Eurostat's powers.'

This new demand for auditing powers for Eurostat came, appropriately, from the European Parliament, and this time, strengthened by the evidence of statistics gone wild in Greece, it managed to get past the Council. Eurostat's September 2010 visit to Greece, which resulted in the final deficit figures which are currently being questioned, was the first time ever that the Directorate made use of its new auditing powers. This resulted in an unprecedented ability to zero in on unreported or misclassified spending and liabilities.

Even in the days leading up to June 2010, the struggle to deny Eurostat its new auditing powers and maintain Governments' 'right' to lie to their citizens was fiercely defended by the Council:
[...] ministers have watered down aspects of the Commission's original proposal. The Commission wanted to require member states to punish their civil servants with “effective, proportionate and dissuasive” sanctions if they deliberately misreported data to Eurostat. Ministers have removed this requirement, because they felt it was an unacceptable infringement of national sovereignty.

The Commission also wanted to place a mandatory obligation on member states to provide Eurostat with “experts in national accounting”. These experts would work with Eurostat on a temporary basis, to help it prepare visits. This was also removed by finance ministers.

The Commission had protested against the changes, but backed down because it did not want to threaten the chance of the legislation being adopted. 
The Commission also wanted to place a mandatory obligation on member states to provide Eurostat with “experts in national accounting”. These experts would work with Eurostat on a temporary basis, to help it prepare visits. This was also removed by finance ministers. The Commission had protested against the changes, but backed down because it did not want to threaten the chance of the legislation being adopted.
Who were the 'key' member states so opposed to further scrutiny of their accounts? Why only the UK, France and Germany. There is no record of how Greece voted but, by the looks of it, that first bunch of proposals was dead on arrival.

TO BE CONTINUED

11 comments:

  1. Vassilis Serafimakis14 August 2015 at 09:05

    You write that a state's deficits are one of the most closely monitored statistics - and you're right, they are. Which only goes to show how deeply and criminally misguided are today's economic analysts and the prevailing economic dogma.

    In reality, a sovereign state's domestic budget balance (i.e. a snapshot of it at any given time) is hardly informative of anything by itself. State budgets are tools and not objectives in themselves; they are used to affect Demand, reduce Unemployment, or serve other purposes. In and by themselves are practicaly meaningless and this maniacal focus on them is our age's tragedy. Worries about a state going bankrupt on its state-currency denominated debt, or about having "problems" servicing it, are entirely absurd. A modern sovereign state, meaning a state with full fiscal and monetary sovereignty, can never be unable to service or default on debt denominated in its currency, as a matter of economic fact. It can only do so, or threaten (its citizens, usually) to do so on the basis of political ideology, exactly as most western governments do, despite them being fully sovereign, e.g. Britain, the US, etc.

    What a pity you waste so much time and effort chasing boogie men and scarecrows. You're obviously learned and honest, but it's time you grow out of the antiquated notion of Macro-as-Micro and acquaint yourself with functional finance and how Macro truly works.

    ReplyDelete
  2. Vassilis Serafimakis14 August 2015 at 09:18

    Manos writes: "it seems to me that Greece operated a 'spend and tax' model (i.e. government set a spending target first and then adjusted taxes to fund this) for most of our modern history."

    And that is precisely, exactly, how any modern, sovereign state should plan its finances as far as domestic spending (i.e. spending in the state currency) is concerned. The state never faces any obstacles to find Money in its own currency, by definition. The only argument against the deployment of fiscal enlargement can be the Inflation argument, the old-and-tired-yet-still-with-us argument of every Monetarist and his Neo-Keynesian cousin.

    Yet, inflation (a term abused on its own by the prevailing dogma, for that matter) can only threaten an economy, ceteris paribus, when we approach Full Employment and at the same time Effective Demand is heating up, which is a situation we can only dream of!..

    So, yes, plan spending first and then "worry" about where the money will come from, yes, that's the correct approach, in fact the only sensible approach*, although from the antics of the immoral, kleptocratic, ignorant political leaders of Greece one would never know it. They were practicing spend-and-tax for mostly other, and mostly nefarious, purposes than our of any understanding of Macroeconomics or state finances.

    * See i.a. Stephanie Bell's "Can Taxes and Bonds Finance Government Spending?" (1998)

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. Ignoring the evangelical tone for a moment, your argument might work when applied to superpowers past and present. I can see why Americans, for example, even Brits might invoke it today.

      I don't find it convincing in the case of Greece, hence the refernce to the Lazaretou and Tuncer papers. States can easily erode people's trust in, and willingness to accept, their own currency. This is not simply possible; historical examples abound, including many Greek examples. When that happens, the ensuing phenomenon is not inflation in any conventional sense (prices of goods going up) - it is simply the devaluation of the medium of payment. This does not require an economy working anywhere near capacity.

      Successive Greek governments in the pre-Euro era knew this. Hence Greece has historically always sought to reinstate trust by joining a currency peg of some sort, only to drop off again as soon as a major emergency (e.g. a war) presented itself. You might argue that this is the case now; fair enough. My objections against adopting a national currency right now are implementation- and timing-related, and comments on the futility of papering over an unreformed economy with money. The principle of the drachma I am not opposed to.

      Delete
    2. Vassilis Serafimakis5 September 2015 at 11:56

      You are arguing that the principles that historically have driven every undeveloped economy, eg 18th-19th century USA, post-war Japan, post-war Korea, "might work [only] when applied to superpowers past and present". Yet we speak of economies BEFORE they were developed, let alone "superpowers".

      As to the fact that dirigisme failed in Greece, this cannot possibly be used as an argument against the practice itself when it has succeeded so spectacularly elsewhere, eg Japan (viz MITI). Greece is bogged down, has been actually during the whole post-war period, by corruption, clientelism, bureaucracy, etc. Yet, despite these illnesses of the Greek polity, the Drachma assisted our economy to grow - so spectacularly, in fact, that the 1953-early 1980s period was dubbed the "Greek miracle": growth rates unsurpassed in Europe. With the currency being pegged to the USD for most of that period, moreover.

      In the early days of that period, there were still many transactions effected through Gold ("líres"). This faded away on account of the growing confidence to the Greek economy itself (way before we entered the EC and the moolah started raining in), which means that your argument about "devaluations of the medium of payment", of which we had aplenty, does not hold water.

      You want to talk external and not domestic "value"? Well, as a matter of fact, the "miracle" was kickstarted with a huge, overnight devaluation of the Greek currency, i.e 50% against the Dollar!..

      Delete
    3. Vassilis Serafimakis5 September 2015 at 12:47

      Manos writes: "My objections against adopting a national currency right now are implementation- and timing-related, and comments on the futility of papering over an unreformed economy with money. The principle of the drachma I am not opposed to."

      Well, using a currency to bring about reforms is as barbaric as it gets . And this demonstrated this every day in Greece.

      Aside from some exaggerations, you are correct about the (dire) deficit of quality in our representatives, our leaders, and our civil servants. You are also correct that the current timing is not exactly opportune for an Exodus.

      But it is infinitely better to get out - now or at any time. I qualify the term: Within the Eurozone as it has being set up, we have precisely zero probability of surviving as an economy. That's zero without any decimal points. The Eurozone may eventually be transformed into a proper, federal, monetary union within a proper, federal union of states - but by that time, the Greek economy will have croaked its last.

      Outside the Eurozone, we have a very small chance of making it. The chance is small precisely on account of the well-known illnesses plaguing our economy and our society, plus the aforementioned scarcity of able politicians and administrators. But any real number is infinitely greater than zero.

      Delete
  3. Wow, cool post. I'd like to write like this too - taking time and real hard work to make a great article...
    but I put things off too much and never seem to get started. Thanks though.

    Try to check my webpage :: 풀싸롱

    (freaky)

    ReplyDelete
  4. This type of article will be able to think and analyzed to the readers thats leads them in a bright future. I think this is one of the most significant information for me. And i’m glad reading your article. But should remark on some general things, The web site style is perfect, the articles is really great. Feel free to visit my website;

    야한동영상

    ReplyDelete
  5. Hi! I just would like to give you a huge thumbs up for the great info you have got right here on this post. I'll be coming back to your site for more soon. Feel free to visit my website; 한국야동닷컴

    ReplyDelete
  6. Such a valuable post. I like it very much and I like your choice words also. I am waiting for your next valuable post. Feel free to visit my website;
    야동

    ReplyDelete
  7. I have read your article; it is very informative and helpful for me. I admire the valuable information you offer in your articles. Thanks for posting it. Feel free to visit my website;
    야설

    ReplyDelete

  8. Wow It is a great contents that I ever seen

    ReplyDelete

Please remember that I am not notified of any comments and will not respond via comments.

Try to keep your criticism constructive and if you don't like something, do tell me how to fix it. If I use any of your suggestions, you will be duly credited.

Although I'm happy to entertain criticism of myself in the comments section, I will not tolerate hate speech. You will be given a written warning and after that I will delete further offending comments.

I will also delete any comments that are clearly randomly generated by third parties for their own promotion.

Occasionally, your comments may land in the spam box, which may cause them to appear with a slight delay as I have to approve them myself.

Thanks in advance for your kind words... and your trolling, if you are so inclined.